Risk management means taking the risks your competitors take.
Sunday, November 30, 2008 at 02:36PM
Skeptic in Sub-prime Mortgage Melt-down

It is frequently said nowadays that the risk management function in Wall Street firms failed because of lack of accurate and credible information and/or executive incompetence. However, the piece of information that generally overwhelms all other information about the riskiness of an investment is whether competitors are taking the risk. Consider this reflection of completely ordinary business behavior from Rubin's Teflon Finally Wears Off:

Mr. Rubin was deeply involved in a decision in late 2004 and early 2005 to take on more risk to boost flagging profit growth, according to people familiar with the discussions. They say he would comment that Citigroup's competitors were taking more risks, leading to higher profits.

The problem isn't limited to investments, of course. Businesses everywhere are having frequent and agonizing meetings of their credit committees to decide whether to accept, for example, the next order for parts from GM or Acme Widget when they have been refused COD, credit insurance, and factoring. Or whether to ship to a large retailer with disturbing credit scores and rumored to be on the edge of BK. If they don't take the order, the consequences for their business may be dire, permanent loss of the customer, for example. Usually, they will wring their hands and take the risk.

Credible technical information about risk is not enough. There must be prudential regulation to keep financial firms "too big to fail" from following the herd onto dangerous ground. I am much more upset about Rubin's failings as a government official than I am about his performance at Citi. The scandal of the subprime mortgage meltdown is not that a few bad apples committed crimes or deceit but that practically everything that happened was perfectly legal.

Update on Monday, December 1, 2008 at 09:55AM by Registered CommenterSkeptic

What got me thinking about this was this excellent Mark Thoma post saying the key missing ingredient in the current financial markets is reliable information about risks, and speculating about whether "trust" could be a short-term substitute.  The "efficient market" hypothesis, the idea that the only requirement for the smooth functioning of markets is good reliable information, comes through implicitly if not explicitly in many of the comments.  My view is that, while good reliable information is important, it is not sufficient.  Other than religious leaders, I can't think of any group more apt than economists to push magic bullet solutions for complex problems.  If they were medical professionals we would happily call them quacks. 

Update on Monday, December 8, 2008 at 09:48PM by Registered CommenterSkeptic

Ezra Klein quotes Henry Blodgett and adds some comments of his own here about conflicts of interest and collective action and the inability of the market itself to correct a collective action. 

Update on Saturday, January 3, 2009 at 10:36AM by Registered CommenterSkeptic

At the height of the bubble, there was so much money to be made that any firm that pulled back because it was nervous about risk would forsake huge short-term gains and lose out to less cautious rivals. The fact that VaR didn’t measure the possibility of an extreme event was a blessing to the executives. It made black swans all the easier to ignore. All the incentives — profits, compensation, glory, even job security — went in the direction of taking on more and more risk, even if you half suspected it would end badly. After all, it would end badly for everyone else too. As the former Citigroup chief executive Charles Prince famously put it, “As long as the music is playing, you’ve got to get up and dance.” Or, as John Maynard Keynes once wrote, a “sound banker” is one who, “when he is ruined, is ruined in a conventional and orthodox way.”

From this fine Joe Nocera article about the rise of Value at Risk ("VaR") modeling in the financial industry.  Update 1/4/09 at 10:00 p.m.: This article is discussed here on Mark Thoma's blog.  Among the points made is this one:  Not only are prices not normally distributed in the past (a key assumption in the VaR models) but events can make futures vastly different from pasts--for example, the Bull's won-lost record vs. the Knicks was not the same before and after the Bulls drafted Michael Jordan.

Update on Saturday, January 3, 2009 at 11:10AM by Registered CommenterSkeptic

Some academic research finding support for the hypothesis that individual investors are inclined to follow the herd, by an adjunct professor at Columbia Business School and former investment banker, is reported on Mark Thoma's blog here.  Just posted, but there are likely to be a lot of good comments. Update 1/1/09 at 9:30 p.m.:  Indeed there were, especially the rejoinder this morning by author Eric Schoenberg.  He points out that investing and not investing both have risks and that while not investing may have a less catastrophic potential outcome, the less-than-catastrophic outcome is highly likely to occur.

Update on Sunday, April 12, 2009 at 02:06PM by Registered CommenterSkeptic

"Leverage cycles happen not because people are stupid, or because they ignore danger signs. It’s in the nature of competition to drive leverage to unsustainable levels, whereupon it collapses, with various effects," according to David Warsh discussing the work of John Geanakoplos. 

Geanakoplos offered a clear and straightforward explanation of the path by which the world had gotten into the current mess. He shed fresh light on the halting steps now being taken to get out of it.

 

For at least a century, he noted, economists have been accustomed to thinking of the interest rate as the most important variable in the economy – lower it to speed things up, raise it to slow them down. Yet especially in times of crisis, collateral demands – alternatively, margin requirements, loan-to-value ratios, leverage rates or “gearing” – become much more important.

 

Everybody knows that when interest rates go down, prices rise. Less widely recognized is that when margin requirements go down – say, the down payment on a house – prices rise too, often even more. Without some form of control, leverage becomes too high in boom times, and asset prices soar disproportionately. When they crash, leverage crashes with them, and then prices suddenly are too low. This is the leverage cycle, Geanakoplos says, and the current crisis is the result of a particularly virulent specimen. Intervention can mitigate its worst effects.

 

Central banks, therefore, should rethink their priorities. The Fed should learn to manage system-wide leverage, he said, reining in on it in ebullient times and propping it up in anxious times, in order to prevent the worst outcomes. Leverage cycles happen not because people are stupid, or because they ignore danger signs. It’s in the nature of competition to drive leverage to unsustainable levels, whereupon it collapses, with various effects.

Article originally appeared on realitybase (http://www.realitybase.org/).
See website for complete article licensing information.