[Corrected 7/15/10 at 0952.]
One of the things we all "know" about global warming is that if we burn "renewable" biomass instead of coal, we can have clean energy that does not contribute to global warming. I've been suspicious about that, and then last week this caught my eye: Massachusetts is revising its rules to disallow to certain biomass combustion plants "green credits" toward the Commonwealth's goal of reducing its carbon footprint. I decided to do some calculations, and it turns out that burning dead trees and some other biomass sources does not necessarily reduce CO2 emissions and may actually increases them, at least in the short term. It's all about inventories of sequestered CO2, as I'll explain.
Assume we have a self-renewing "forest" of 40 trees, each of which sprouted in a different year and each of which will die on its 40th birthday (sproutday?). Assume further that each tree grows at a linear rate and incorporates into its structure 5 tons of CO2 by the day it dies, i.e., 250 pounds per year. Finally, assume that Uupon its death, each tree decays at a linear rate of 500 pounds per year, with the assistance of termites, fungi, and other critters, and 20 years after its death has released all of its CO2 back to the atmosphere. Thus, while our forest is in this steady state, we have 40 live trees containing an average of 2.5 tons of CO2 each, for a total of 100 tons, and 20 dead trees each containing an average of 2.5 tons of CO2, another 100 50 tons. Our little forest keeps sequestered, year after year, 200 150 tons of CO2.
Now, let's build a biomass combustion facility at the edge of our forest. Each year we will harvest the tree that died that year and burn it to produce electricity, releasing 5 tons of CO2 to the atmosphere. The trees that died in prior years go on naturally decomposing, but after 20 years they are all gone, and 100 50 tons of CO2 formerly sequestered in our stock of dead trees is all back in the atmosphere. After that, burning each tree as it dies will not further increase the amount of CO2 in the atmosphere, because the rest of the forest assimilates 5 tons per year of CO2. However, to get to that new steady state we will have destroyed the 100 50-ton CO2 dead-tree sink, the same size as the one in our live trees. The planet will be worse off by 100 50 tons of CO2.
Would the planet nevertheless be better off if the wood burning backed out some coal combustion? That would clearly be true in the 21st and later years after loss of the dead-tree CO2 sink, but what about during those first 20 years? When wood is burned, it releases less energy than coal because the carbon in wood is already "partially oxidized" from pure C to cellulose, a polymer of glucose (C6 H10 O5) units. Wood pulp has a higher heating value of 7,510 Btu/lb and will release 1.630 lbs of CO2 (1 x 264/162). Pure carbon, which is responsible for nearly all the energy content in coal, yields 14,500 Btu/lb and releases 3.667 lbs of CO2 (1 x 44/12). Thus, burning wood releases 86% as much CO2 as burning coal for the same energy output, not a very big advantage. (By similar calculations, one can show that burning natural gas is far better for the planet in the short term than burning dead trees, because natural gas releases only about 56% as much CO2 per unit of energy as does coal.)
One general lesson to take away from this model is that, in steady-state conditions, there may be as much CO2 sequestered in dead biomass as in live biomass—as in any plant the CO2 content goes from zero to maximum and then back to zero. (If the growth and/or decay processes are non-linear, the two sectors may not have exactly equal CO2 content.) The dead tree sink could be either larger or smaller than the live-tree sink, depending on rates of growth and decay which, of course, are probably not linear. I assume tree decay is relatively rapid in the tropics and relatively slow in high latitudes. My impression (only an impression—I haven't done my homework on this) is that some folks consider only the CO2 content of live biomass in their efforts to show project benefits. Oh, and here's another counter-intuitive fact: Turning trees into lumber and incorporating them into long-lived structures may be better for the planet than letting the trees die and decay more quickly in their natural habitats.
This analysis does not necessarily indict every "biomass" project. For example, if barren desert were covered with tanks of cultivated algae to produce biofuels, there would be no destruction of existing sinks of CO2, and the process could be very "climate friendly" if it displaced fossil fuels. However, one should perhaps compare that project with providing water to the area to develop a self-sustaining forest as a CO2 sink, which might be an even better way to slow down global warming. I mean only to show that one cannot assume biomass projects are climate friendly—you have to do your homework and get the accounting right. Heads up to my friends in northern Michigan: Traverse City Power & Light is moving ahead with two projects based on biomass from trees.
Update on Thursday, October 7, 2010 at 09:44AM by
Skeptic
Sequestering CO2 by turning trees into lumber is old technology, but at the University of Illinois they're proposing to turn corn stover into building materials dubbed "CornBoard."
Update on Monday, November 8, 2010 at 08:42AM by
Skeptic
Here's a specific case where growing biofuels may increase CO2 emissions by leading directly or indirectly to clearing and cultivation of wild lands.
BRUSSELS, Nov 8 (Reuters) – European plans to promote biofuels will drive farmers to convert 69,000 square km of wild land into fields and plantations, depriving the poor of food and accelerating climate change, a report warned on Monday.
The impact equates to an area the size of the Republic of Ireland.
As a result, the extra biofuels that Europe will use over the next decade will generate between 81 and 167 percent more carbon dioxide than fossil fuels, says the report.
Update on Tuesday, July 26, 2011 at 10:55AM by
Skeptic
Here is a post on Climate Progress that includes estimates on CO2 sequestration of clear-cutting and replanting forests in order to harvest wood products. It considers CO2 sequestered in dead trees, in dead trees, and in the wood products.
Update on Saturday, November 30, 2013 at 11:11AM by
Skeptic
In 2011, EPA kicked off a rulemaking process to govern how stationary sources account for CO2 emissions when they burn biomass. Recently 41 scientists organized by NRDC have sent this letter to the rule makers stating that "studies conducted in different regions of the U.S. have found that burning whole trees in conventional, standalone power plants increases carbon emissions relative to fossil fuels for 35 to 100 years or more." (The delay may not be so long for faster-growing biomass like grasses.) In addition, the letter states that burning typical biomass with a water content of about 50% emits more CO2 per unit of usable energy than does burning coal. Biomass harvesting processes can also release CO2 from soils. ClimateProgress has a broader discussion here.
The closer we get to the real issues, the more interested I get in GCC legislation. Although showing promise, Stavins is still behind the curve in that regard.
There is probably no more important political fact than that carbon pricing is very bad for coal interests, nearly neutral for petroleum, and very good for natural gas. This results from starting by appeasing the god of economic efficiency with a system that generates a single price for all CO2 emissions regardless of source. That leads to the drama in Congress about trying to prevent the shuttering of the coal mining industry and write-off of coal-fired power plants (e.g., by making it possible to substitute “offsets” by “preserving” Amazon rain forests, etc.) and/or obscuring the attack on coal by assigning to the “market” responsibility for determining outcomes (so that elected representatives of the people can deny responsibility for lost livelihoods). A more realistic legislative approach might be to buy all the coal mines and turn them into wildlife preserves and soccer fields.
In support of the first sentence above, consider the following. According to CBO, a price of $191 per ton of CO2 would not reduce consumption of highway fuels at all below what they will be under existing CAFÉ standards. To see why this is so, consider how the $80/ton price recently proposed by Joseph Stiglitz would affect coal and gasoline. A ton of typical steam coal contains about 1400 lbs. of carbon, which will turn into 5,133 lbs. (2.57 tons) of CO2. If CO2 is assessed at $80 per ton, the price of a ton of coal would increase by $205. Since the national average coal price was $31.26 in 2008, that price increase would cause electricity generators to close their coal-fired plants as soon as possible and switch to natural gas, renewables, and (maybe) nuclear.
In contrast, $80 per ton for CO2 would raise the price of gasoline by only $0.80 per gallon (a gallon of gasoline generates ~20 lbs. or 1/100 of a ton of CO2). Obviously, that won't discourage use of highway fuels very much even though it would cost US consumers $110 billion per year in the aggregate. In the US, about 60% of petroleum is converted into gasoline; other major products are motor diesel, jet fuel, home heating oil, and a variety of industrial uses, none of which were addressed by the CBO report; however, I doubt a price increase of 20-30% in these fuels would dramatically reduce consumption of them either, but you use your own business judgment. Bottom line: a price of $80/ton of CO2 could cause an INCREASE in consumption of petroleum products as utilities switch from coal fired units to gas turbines (which were originally designed to burn petroleum distillates, not natural gas, in the stratosphere).
So why does the petroleum industry seem so upset by cap/trade? I suggest they are not really upset but are just routinely opposing and exploiting opportunity. They have a budget and team for federal government relations and will devote it to whatever issues on are on the table, which at the moment includes threatened government “interference” in their business—even if the “interference” might help their business. In contrast to this routine opposition, if you want to see what a petroleum industry full court press looks like, if you want to see the sky over DC darkened by corporate jets and the finance chairs of Senate re-election campaigns worked to exhaustion booking contributions, bring a repeal of the IRC oil depletion allowance close to a floor vote. Furthermore, it is routine in Washington to demand something of value in exchange for any legislative initiative that can be plausibly claimed to have an adverse effect on one's industry. This isn’t a crisis for the oil industry—it’s an opportunity.
From EPA’s most recent report on US contributions to global climate change, using 2006 data: CO2 accounts for 85% of total greenhouse gas emissions, 94% of which come from burning fossil fuels, and about 41% of that comes from coal. If petroleum consumption will not change substantially and natural gas consumption will increase, any aggregate net change must come from reducing coal consumption. Legislation that does not respond head-on to this reality may pave the way to re-election of incumbents but won’t ameliorate the GCC problem.